History of the Human and Nature Relationship, Discovery of Greenhouse Effect and Awareness of the Environmental Problem
Source: By:Author(s)
DOI: https://doi.org/10.30564/jesr.v4i3.3120
Abstract:The evolution of man and nature relationship during human history has allowed human beings to be sheltered from the threats of their natural environments and has permitted them to exercise their powers there but has against part the breakdown of this relationship because of the excessive exploitation of natural resources, discharges and waste that cause nature pollution. This rupture caused climate change due to the evolution of the production model from the primitive model to the capitalist model. The objective of this paper is to shed light on the evolution of the relationship between human beings and their natural environment and the awareness of the climate change problem. This research allows appreciating and comparing the effectiveness of the resolutions that can help researchers understanding the climate change context, serve as a springboard for empirical studies, and represent a decision tool for policymakers. To this end, we use a knowledge synthesis methodology to make an inventory of our research problem.
References:[1]Arrhenius, S. (1910). L'évolution des mondes. Librairie polytechnique. [2] Bargaoui, S. A., Liouane, N., & Nouri, F. Z. (2014). Environmental impact determinants: An empirical analysis based on the STIRPAT model. Procedia-Social and Behavioral Sciences, 109, 449-458. [3] Baudot, P. Bley, D. Brun, B. Pagezy, H. and Vernazza-Licht, N. (1997). Impact de l’ Homme sur les milieux naturels : perceptions et mesures, pp.208, Travaux de la Société d’Ecologie Humaine, 2-9507852-7-1. ffhal-01290258f. [4] Billaudot, B., & Destais, G. (2009). Les analyses de la durabilité en économie : fondements théoriques et implications normatives. In Colloque" Pour la suite du monde : développement durable ou décroissance soutenable ?", HEC Montréal. [5] Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. In Classic papers in natural resource economics (pp. 87-137). Palgrave Macmillan, London. [6] Costanza, R. (1991). Ecological economics: a research agenda. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 2(2), 335-357. [7] Costanza, R., d'Arge, R., De Groot, R., Farber, S., Grasso, M., Hannon, B., ... & Van Den Belt, M. (1997). The value of the world's ecosystem services and natural capital. nature, 387(6630), 253-260. [8] Daly, H. E. (1990). Toward some operational principles of sustainable development. Ecological economics, 2(1), 1-6. [9] De Muizon, C. (2001). Walking with whales. Nature, 413(6853), 259-260. [10] Denis, B. (2003). Les monstres froids à l'épreuve du réchauffement de la planète. Annuaire français de relations internationales, 2003(4). [11] Faucheux, S., & O’Connor, M. (1999). Choix technologiques et menaces environnementales : une nécessaire gouvernance concertative. Paris, Université de Versailles Saint-Quentin-en-Yvelines. Cahiers du C3ED, (99-03), 38. [12] Godard, O., & Salles, J. M. (1991). Entre nature et société, les jeux de l'irréversibilité dans la construction économique et sociale du champ de l'environnement. [13] Hardin, G. (1968). The Tragedy. art. cit, 1243. [14] Hartwick, J. M. (1997). Paying down the environmental debt. Land Economics, 508-515. [15] Hotelling, H. (1931). The economics of exhaustible resources. Journal of political Economy, 39(2), 137- 175. [16] IPCC, Climate change 2001: the scientific Basis, 2001. [17] IPCC, Summary for decision makers, 2008. [18] Jean-Marie Harribey, (2002), « Le développement durable est-il soutenable ?», Séminaire de l’OFCE, p21. [19] Jevons, W. S. (1866). The Coal Question; An Inquiry Concerning the Progress of the Nation, and the Probable Exhaustion of our Coal-Mines. Fortnightly, 6(34), 505-507. [20] Lauriola, V. (1997). Le développement soutenable de l'école de Londres: une approche «orwellienne»?. Economies et sociétés (Paris), 31(4), 71-89. [21] Malthus, T. R. (1798). An essay on the principle of population as it affects the future improvement of society, with remarks on the speculations of Mr Godwin, M. Condorcet, and other writers. London : J. Johnson. [22] Mohen, J. P. (2006). Climat et néolithisation de l'Europe méditerranéenne. Comptes Rendus Palevol, 5(1- 2), 453-462. [23] Perelman, M. (1975). Natural resources and agriculture under capitalism: Marx's economic model. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 57(4), 701-704. [24] Petty, W., & Graunt, J. (1899). The Economic Writings of Sir William Petty: Together with the Observations Upon the Bills of Mortality, More Probably by Captain John Graunt (Vol. 1). The University Press. [25] Quesnay, F. (1758). « Tableau économique » avec son explication, ou Extrait des économies royales de Sully. Paris 1758. [26] Ramsey, F. P. (1928). A mathematical theory of saving. The economic journal, 38(152), 543-559. [27] Raymond, Barre. (1959). Economie politique. Thémis, PUF, 85. [28] Ricardo, D. (1891). Principles of political economy and taxation. G. Bell and sons. [29] Swaney, J. A. (1987). Elements of a neoinstitutional environmental economics. Journal of Economic Issues, 21(4), 1739-1779. [30] Tyndall, J. (1860). VII. Note on the transmission of radiant heat through gaseous bodies. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London, (10), 37-39. [31] United Nations. (1992). United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change. [32] Walras, L. (1880). Théorie mathématique du prix des terres et de leur rachat par l. Bulletin de la Société Vaudoise des Sciences Naturelles, 17. [33] Zeder, M. (2012). The domestication of animals. Journal of Anthropological Research, 68(2), 161-190. Retrieved May 15, 2021, from http://www. jstor.org/stable/23264664.